Comments

Created 9/28/1998
Go to Brad DeLong's
Home Page

Teaching | Writing | Career | Politics | Book Reviews | Information Economy | Economists | Multimedia | Students | Fine Print | Other | My Jobs

Feedback is always very welcome...


How Fast Is Modern Economic Growth?

J. Bradford DeLong

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Weekly Letter
October 6, 1998
delong@econ.berkeley.edu
http://www.j-bradford-delong.net


The pace of productivity growth in the United States since the end of the Civil War has averaged about 1.6% per year--or so historical estimates (Kendrick, 1961) and the official statistics of the Department of Commerce say. This average annual growth rate implies that output per worker doubles every 44 years, and that in the 133 years since the Civil War, productivity has doubled three times. This means that Americans today can make the same goods that our predecessors made in one-eighth the time (Cox and Alm, 1997; Baumol, Blackman, and Wolff 1989), and would seem to imply that an American a century and a third ago would have had to possess eight times the average worker's real income then to be as well off as someonewith the average worker's income is today.

Thus only the top 2% of the American population then would have had a material standard of living equivalent to or higher than that of the average American now.

Now such a pace of modern economic growth would be blazingly fast in historical perspective. No other century has seen anything near such a pace of productivity improvement. Even the century and a third from the invention of the first steam engine to the end of the Civil War saw at most one doubling of productivity--not three.

Yet for the past several decades evidence has been mounting that official statistics and historical estimates significantly understate economic growth, and that modern economic growth since the mid-nineteenth century has been much more rapid than our standard measures suggest. This Economic Letter explains the nature of some of the controversy over measuring economic growth and productivity.

 

Taking the measure

The process by which standard measures of output or productivity understate economic growth is straightforward. Take all the final goods and services produced and sold over a year and divide it by the number of workers. That yields a measure of GDP per worker, which today is $60,000 per year. Back in the late 1860s, American GDP per worker (measured at 1998 prices) was some $7,500 per year. This number is computed by taking all the final goods and services produced and sold in a year in the late 1860s, then valuing each of these goods and services at today's prices, then adding up their 1998-dollar values, and dividing by the number of workers. So GDP per worker in 1867 at some $7,500 (at 1998 prices) was one-eighth of today's value.

But this is not necessarily the most useful measure of production per worker back in 1867. Does it reallymake sense to compare the way a worker in 1867 could spend the equivalent of 7500 1998 purchasing-power dollars per year with the way a worker in 1998 would spend $7500 per year? A worker with $7500 today surely would spend some of it on modern medicines such as antibiotics, some on a television set every few years and the electricity to run it, some on bus trips, some on consumer durables (such as a stove), and a large proportion on food and rent for a small, poorly maintained and inconveniently located apartment (which would, even so, probably have central heating).

The average worker back in 1867 could buy none of these things.

Thus there is a sense in which the average worker back in 1867 was much worse off than a worker today would be with an annual income of $7,500. Back then, no worker could spend a cent on modern entertainment or communications or transportation technologies, not to mention a toaster or on the electric utilities to run it. No worker could spend a cent on a telephone, or on an apartment with central heating.

Perhaps a more fruitful way to conceptualize the material standard of living of average Americans back in the late 1860s would be to think of them as having to spend the $7500 exclusively on commodities that have been in existence for more than a century: food (although not freeze-dried or mechanically processed), clothing (although not artificial fibers), and shelter (but not on anything invented since the middle of the nineteenth century).

How large is the value of Americans' ability today to use and consume all of the goods and services that have been invented since the middle of the nineteenth century? How valuable is the increase in technological capabilities--the ability not to make goods more cheaply than they were made a century ago, but to produce new goods and new types of services like central heating, electric lights, fluoridated toothpaste, toaster ovens, antibiotics, CAT scans, synthetic fiber-blend clothes, radios, intercontinental telephones, xerox machines, notebook computers, automobiles, and steel-framed skyscrapers?

 

Finding the answer in literary criticism

Here I believe there is more insight to be gained by adopting the viewpoint not of an economist but of a literary critic, and examining Edward Bellamy's (1887) Looking Backward. Although the prose is wooden to our sensibilities, this book was a best-seller in the late nineteenth century: it gave a very hopeful vision of how economic growth would bring us to utopia before the end of the twentieth century.

Bellamy's narrator is carried forward in time from 1895 to 2000 and marvels at the future. At one point in the novel his hosts of the future ask, "Would you like to hear some music?" The narrator expects his host to play the piano--a social accomplishment of upper-class women around 1900. Instead, the narrator is stupefied to find that his host "merely touched one or two screws," and immediately the room was "filled with music; filled, not flooded, for, by some means, the volume of melody had been perfectly graduated to the size of the apartment. 'Grand!' I cried. 'Bach must be at the keys of that organ; but where is the organ?'" He learns that his host has called the orchestra on the telephone.

In Bellamy's late twentieth-century utopia, you can dial up a live orchestra and then put it on the speakerphone. You even have a choice of orchestras: there are four playing at any moment. Bellamy's narrator then says, "if we [in the nineteenth century] could have devised an arrangement for providing everybody with music in their homes, perfect in quality, unlimited in quantity, suited to every mood, and beginning and ceasing at will, we should have considered the limit of human felicity already attained...."

What if someone were to take Edward Bellamy or his protagonist to Tower Records today? Or to buy a large-screen projection TV and then to Blockbuster Video? His heart would stop. Yet we do not daily give thanks for our cassette players and our CD collections for having brought us to the limit of human felicity. We rarely think about them at all: we take them very much for granted.

Thus the answer implicit in Looking Backward is that modern economic growth has been so great as to carry us off the scale of measurement that past generations could imagine: from Bellamy's point of view, from the perspective of only one century in the past, we today have technological capabilities for production that should have carried us beyond "the limit of human felicity." Thus in some respects, there is no one in the America of 1867 who had then the same material standard of living as an average American today. Neither Junius Spencer Morgan nor Jay Cooke in 1867 could buy access to late twentieth century medicines, or to the products of modern entertainment industries, or to the products of our information technology industries, or even to our utilities. Nathan Meyer Rothschild, the richest man in the world in the first half of the nineteenth century, died of an abscess that could have been cured with less than $10 of antibiotics and fifteen minutes of a nurse's time today (Landes, 1998). So, if the question we ask is, "How great a multiple of average income would someone had to have had in the past in order to have the same material standard of living today?" then perhaps the most plausible answer is, "Modern growth is so fast, it's off the scale."

 

Estimating the inestimable?

Still, we do look for a measure. For example, Nordhaus (1997) attempted to calculate the long-run decline in the real price of illumination. He investigated not the price of a single good (like a light bulb) but instead the price of the service that the good is used to deliver (casting light so that you can see). Nordhaus concluded that traditional indices of the price of light would miss the extraordinary upward leaps in productivity that took place whenever one technology of illumination was succeeded by another. For the case of illumination, this unmeasured technological progress and economic growth was fastest in the 50 years around the end of the nineteenth century.

The growing body of literature on the consumer surplus from increases in product variety reinforces this point: the increase in consumer welfare created from gaining access to new goods and new types of goods (even if the prices of old goods and the level of nominal income remain unchanged) appears considerable. Trachtenberg (1990), Nordhaus (1997), and other studies collected in Bresnehan and Raff (1997) reveal a pattern of large economic benefits from the increase in the types of goods that consumers can buy, benefits that are not captured by standard price increases.

If a single number on the underestimation of productivity growth is required, however, one worth considering comes from the Boskin Commission's (1998) findings on the reform of the Consumer Price Index. The Boskin Commission estimates that price inflation has been overestimated and productivity growth underestimated by about 1 percentage point per year. Based on this estimate, productivity would have doubled every 27 years instead of every 44 years, so we would have seen five doublings since the Civil War instead of three. Thus, productivity today would be thirty-two times, and not eight times, what it was at the beginning of the Gilded Age.

But suppose we turn the question around: what fraction of average income in the present would give the same standard of living as average income in the past? Extrapolating from the Boskin Commission's conclusions would suggest that a worker with an average income immediately after the Civil War had the same material standard of living as an American worker with an annual income of $1,800 today. That seems very unreasonable. Would anyone really change the solid middle-class existence of an American farmer just after the Civil War for the material standard of living attainable on $1,800 a year today? For the poor, the claim that their real incomes have been vastly boosted by the increase in choice and by the invention of new types of commodities seems to be simply wrong: if you cannot afford to consume the modern information, communications, entertainment, and transportation technologies, you can hardly be said to have benefited from their invention.

The magnitude of the benefits today's Americans can be said to receive from their power to use the new goods and new types of goods that have been invented over the past century depends on how high they rank in the income distribution, and drops off rapidly as you approach the bottom.

 

Conclusion

The overall conclusion, however, remains clear: from the standpoint of anyone above the poverty line, modern economic growth over the past century has been significantly faster than standard measures record, because standard measures omit much of the benefit to material standards of living from the explosion of human technological capabilities over the past century. But how much more? Obtaining good solid numerical estimates of how much more is difficult, and creating estimates on which a near-consensus might be attained would be impossible.

Thus national income accountants continue to report the standard estimates--the ones on which near-consensus can be attained. But we should not let the fact that the standard estimates tell us that productivity growth over the past century and a bit has averaged 1.6 percent per year to blind us to the fact that true improvements in material standards of living for those at, not too far below, and above average incomes have been and still are much more rapid.


References

Baumol, W., S. Blackman, and E. Wolff. 1989. Productivity and American Leadership: The Long View. Cambridge: MIT Press.

Bellamy, E. 1887. Looking Backward. New York: New American Library (reprint).

Boskin, M., et al. 1998. "Consumer Prices, the Consumer Price Index, and the Cost of Living." Journal of Economic Perspectives 12 (Winter) pp. 3-26.

Bresnehan, T., and D. Raff. 1997. The Economics of New Goods. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Cox, W. M., and R. Alm. 1997. "Time Well Spent: The Declining Real Cost of Living in America." Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Annual Report.

Kendrick, D. 1961. Productivity Trends in the United States. New York: NBER.

Landes, D. 1998. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich and Others So Poor. New York: W.W. Norton.

Nordhaus, W. 1997. "Do Real Output and Real Wage Measures Capture Reality? The History of Lighting Suggests Not." In The Economics of New Goods, eds. Bresnahan and Raff. pp. 26-69. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Trajtenberg, M. 1990. Economic Analysis of Product Innovation: The Case of CT Scanners. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.


Feedback is always very welcome...


Professor of Economics J. Bradford DeLong, 601 Evans, #3880
University of California at Berkeley
Berkeley, CA 94720-3880
(510) 643-4027 phone (510) 642-6615 fax
delong@econ.berkeley.edu
http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/

This document: http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/Comments/FRBSF_fast_growth.html

Search This Website